2015年8月25日火曜日

2015-08-25 Econometric Modeling as a Strategic Weapon








Dr. Michael Sinkinson of the University of Pennsylvania (Wharton School)


Econometric Modeling as a Strategic Weapon

An Assistant Professor of Business Economics and Public Policy at the University of Pennsylvania, Michael Sinkinson specializes in Applied Microeconomics and Industrial Organization. He has researched market structure in the media, technology, and telecommunications industries, publishing work in leading journals like The American Economic Review. An outstanding teacher as well as research, Dr. Sinkinson was listed among the best 40 business school professors in the 2014 Poets & Quants rankings. Dr. Sinkinson received his Ph.D. in Business Economics from Harvard University.



1.   You have conducted several studies of the effects of printed newspapers on politics. Why does this field of inquiry interest you? To what other areas have you applied econometric analysis? What areas of U.S. government policy do you feel could benefit from more extensive and / or rigorous use of such analysis?

I find newspapers and the media really interesting because they cut across everything. Media is about information. With poor or biased information, no government, firm, or individual can make the right decision. For this reason, I find that media is central to everything. For example, some coauthors and I looked at the effect of media on politics. We looked at how newspapers compete, how they choose the types of viewpoints they represent in the market. We also looked at the impacts of newspapers on political outcomes. For example, we actually showed that when more newspapers are being read in a market, more people are actually participating in the political process. If you think democracy is a good system, that is a big deal. Right away, you see that the news media are important because of their informational value.  I think media is fascinating; it touches everything. That’s one area of interest where I have done research over time.

I’ve also looked at other areas. I would describe my research agenda as looking at areas of non-price competition in the fields of technology, media, and telecom. What I mean by non-price competition is that I kind of assume that firms get prices right:  the prices that clear the market. That is going to happen given a set of products. So then the relevant question is, “What is the set of products that go to market?” Taking the case of newspapers, they would think about the viewpoint they will represent. What are they going to choose as the characteristics of their paper?

In telecom, I conducted a study looking at exclusive contracts. Wireless companies sign exclusive contracts with different hand-set manufacturers. They choose to make products available only from certain carriers. This is a form of non-price competition. Prices will then be set in the market to rationalize that competition, but why do some manufacturers only use some carriers? For example, why did Apple not offer their hand set to other carriers? When Apple launched the iPhone in the U.S., it was available only from AT&T. This same situation applies in Japan, as well. Softbank was the exclusive provider for a long time there. This is another form of non-price competition.

A more recent project is on advertising, another important form of non-price competition. In the U.S., prescription drugs are advertised on television. Few countries allow this form of advertising, a very American phenomenon. This is a form of non-price competition:  companies compete against their rivals by making information available directly to consumers through TV ads. I wanted to understand the effect of this form of non-price competition, which is a great area in terms of policy analysis. We are finding that the ads generate a positive spillover, a positive externality in economic parlance: Consumers who see ads about drugs go to physicians to consult with their doctors about health problems. By doing so, they enjoy benefits that were not necessarily intended by the pharmaceutical company that ran the ads.

In regard to your question about what areas of policy would benefit from more economic analysis, I would say that this area of externalities is a big one. What I mean, specifically, is lots of things firms do create positive spillovers. Society should encourage companies to do this more. The area is a difficult one to quantify, but a great opportunity for the application of economic research to policy. For example, the U.S. government is currently debating whether or not to extend the research and development tax credit. For a long time, economists have argued that the credit should be made permanent because we feel that R&D has a positive spillover on society. This area has a tendency to become politicized quickly, but the area is one were economists can provide research on the right level of subsidies to generate desired spillovers.



2.   Can you give us an overview you of your research on pricing and entry incentives with exclusive contracts using data from smart phones? What motivated the research? To what extent can the results be applied to other industries? To other countries like Japan?

In 2007, when Apple launched the iPhone in the U.S., AT&T was the exclusive provider. I wanted an iPhone, but Verizon was my service provider. To get an iPhone, I had to switch carriers. Because AT&T had terrible service, I could not receive phone calls in my office. The quality was terrible, too. I began to think, “This makes no sense? A, Why would Apple make the iPhone available only through one carrier, and B, why would they choose a carrier that did not even provide a reliable signal?” My iPhone had become an expensive answering machine. It did nothing but collect messages. This frustration prompted me to reflect on the theory behind why Apple would sign an exclusive contract with AT&T, leading to a piece of research that shows something interesting. If all carriers offered hand-sets from all manufacturers, the only differentiation would be the service carriers offer. That would be good for consumers because you get perfect competition. If you have an exclusive contract, you can obviously charge a bit more; you are not competing against a bundle from another carrier with the same handset. Not only can I raise the price of an iPhone that is exclusive, but as a second-level effect, all other carriers can raise the prices on their handsets—even the Blackberries. The whole industry benefits. My research showed that this effect could be very large. I collected data from wireless carriers to show just how large.

Along the way, I made an additional discovery. I learned which provider would be willing to pay the most for exclusivity. Why did AT&T, and not Verizon, the largest carrier, pay more? When you work out the theory, you realize that the second-best or biggest in the industry can has a lot more to lose if the leading competitor lands the exclusive contract. In the U.S., Verizon has a very strong network. They were not going to lose much if they did not get the iPhone. Because AT&T had a weaker network, they would have been really hurt had Verizon offered the iPhone. For this reason, AT&T was willing to pay a lot.

Analogizing to Japan, NTT Docomo was the largest carrier. Softbank purchased Vodafone’s wireless network. In some sense, Softbank was the insurgent. If the iPhone had been exclusive to NTT, Softbank would have been in trouble. They would have had no way to compete. So Softbank was willing to pay a lot to have an exclusive iPhone contract. It gave them a way to differentiate their product from NTT. If you survey world markets, you realize that Apple used a similar strategy in just about all of them. In China, Apple launched with the second largest carrier, and in other countries too, they launched with the second-best rival because those companies were willing to pay the most.

I studied this effect in the context of telecom, but other economists are studying the effect in other industries. The same problem applies to video game systems. There, the problem is more complicated because you might purchase ten different games when you buy an X-Box. The ratio changes in this case. It is no longer one-to-one as in the case of handsets and wireless carriers. Researchers have looked at exclusive video games for different platforms. If you think about what Netflix, Hulu, and Amazon are doing right now with exclusive content, the idea is the same. Netflix is trying to differentiate itself from rivals by featuring exclusive content. This move really changes the dynamic of the market.



3.   As I am sure you know, the Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe has introduced major macroeconomic reforms under the rubric of Abenomics. Based on your expertise in microeconomics, can you make recommendations to specific industries like mobile telecom and consumer electronics for increasing their global competitiveness, thereby intensifying the effect of macroeconomic reforms already in place?

I need to caveat that international trade and macroeconomics are not my forte. The policy gave incentives to companies to modernize, to invest. I think this is a good thing. Realistically, with industries like consumer electronics and telecom, the market is global. In the end, the winners are going to be the most efficient, highest-quality producers. I think one of your other questions relates to protectionist policies, bailouts, and the like. Firms need to be competitive. Creating incentives to invest in equipment are effective in the long run, so I do think the policies will be good for firms. Firms need to be given the correct incentives to ensure that they will survive the shakeout and still be around in ten or twenty years.



4.   As internet technologies evolve and improve, more traditional newspaper and magazine publishing companies are having difficulties surviving. Even the Washington Post has been acquired by Amazon founder Jeff Bezos, as I am sure you know. What are your suggestions for helping print-media companies survive in the current era of technology-driven turbulence?

The reality is that these companies may not survive in their current form. Historically, printed media had geographic protections. In general, you were isolated in your own market. If you were a newspaper in Cleveland, Ohio, you were exposed to competition from other newspapers in the area. The first hint that the climate was changing was the cable news channels. All of  a sudden, the papers and television stations in Cleveland catering to local tastes had to compete with cable news channels broadcasting news from all over the country. Local viewers began switching to channels and stations that offered content better tailored to their interests.

The internet has taken this trend to the limit. Now, every view point is accessible. Regardless of your tastes or interests, you can find a blog or other information sources that cater to you. Catering to a local market is now difficult to do as a result. Different people in Cleveland want different content in their news. Blogs or other online media that cater to a particular taste are going to scoop up readers sharing that taste in all local markets. These media will cobble together a base, leavening most of the print media out in the cold. The few papers like The New York Times and Wall Street Journal that have become successful achieve this success by A, becoming national to solve the geography problem and B, offering very high quality. They are able to attract high-end readers willing to pay a premium for a high-quality product. This strategy is not useful for a local paper in Cleveland, Ohio.

If you look at what is happening right now, there are a few choices. Some papers are becoming online outlets. The Seattle Post-Intelligencer has shut down print operations to become an online news outlet. Sounds good, but they had to cut down their newsroom considerably, as well. When you do that, you become a fundamentally different publication, something that could be bad for consumers. Because journalists provide a public good, exposing scandals, for example, this progression is not necessarily a good one. But in terms of a business model, it is one of only a few choices. The old business model just does not work anymore. Going forward, a lot of traditional newspapers may not survive.

The only other option to going online is to become ultra-local, something the San Diego newspaper is trying to do. They are sending journalists into neighborhoods to report on everything. Ultra-local content is another strategy. The San Diego paper is trying it out, but I do not know if they are sure that it will work. We are definitely going to see new business models emerge because even ones from ten years ago are no longer viable.



5.   You once quipped, "If I weren't a B-school professor, I would be an entrepreneur." What attracts you to entrepreneurship? Have you done research in this field? What did you learn about entrepreneurship from your part-time work as a bartender during graduate school?

Let me start with your question about why I am attracted to entrepreneurship. What I like about it and academic work as a professor is the freedom to pursue your interests. For better and worse, you are your own boss. Like your failures, your successes are your own. I like that personal freedom and responsibility to pursue whatever I like to do. Academia is ideal for people like me. If I think a question is interesting, like why I can not get an iPhone from Verizon, I can explore the question, research it. This attribute that attracts me to academia also applies to entrepreneurship. In this sense, I think the two fields are actually related. In academia, you are an entrepreneur:  You have kind of your own brand, and you are judged by your own work. If you do not perform well, you will not be tenured. Academia is like being an entrepreneur with a bit more of a safety net. This similarity to academia is the reason why I think I would be drawn to entrepreneurship.

To answer your question about what I learned as a bartender, one, being on the front lines, I gained a lot of direct experiences with the problems and challenges of the business. It was a great way to understand the market and industry and an opportunity to learn how to solve problems. As I bartender, I saw all kinds of problems. Because owners and managers may not see them, you have to be the problem solver all of the time. If you really want to make money as an entrepreneur, you should find a problem that no one has solved, and solve it. This is one lesson I learned from being a bartender. I also learned that I did not want to be a bartender for the rest of my life. The experience motivated me to work hard to further my education so I did not have to be a bartender forever.



6.   Students have noted that you have never been asked a question that you have been unable to answer in considerable detail. How did you acquire this extensive knowledge at such a young age? What are your suggestions for young scholars and business professionals on dealing with information overload and increasing their retention of useful knowledge?

People who have a strong curiosity about the world tend to be drawn to academia and teaching. They love learning. For these people, it is a life-long pursuit. I am glad that students feel that I possess this curiosity, because it is an aspiration.

Retaining information is a challenge. I sometimes have difficulty getting work done due to information overload. I am constantly being bombarded with emails. For me, the answer was the decision to block off days. I do not hold meetings, I do not respond to emails on these days or check emails frequently, either. I just focus on my research. I go to a white board, and I focus. For some people, the act of putting down their phone seems unnatural. But I think that it is important to do so, especially if you want to solve difficult or complex problems. You cannot be distracted every five to ten minutes.

I am also a morning person. During the semester when I am teaching, I usually awake at 5:30 am. Because I teach my first class at 9 am, I have a few hours. Due to the early time, no one is emailing me or knocking on my door. No one is calling me, either. My office is quiet, allowing me to concentrate. I can ensure that my lectures are well prepared. These morning hours when no one is trying to contact me are the best time to work. I need time during the day and the week when I am not being bombarded to think and solve some problems.



7.   In the review written about you in Poets & Quants, where you are listed as one of the best 40 best business-school professors under 40, you explained that teaching has been a life-long interest. What aspects of teaching do you enjoy? What have you learned from your students? What aspects of teaching do you find tedious or displeasurable?

I enjoy interacting with highly engaged, intelligent students. At Wharton, I teach three classes a year to roughly 200 students. All sharp, they do not let me get away with anything. To really teach a topic, you must first master it completely. Hearkening back to your previous question about my detailed knowledge of a broad range of topics, I enjoy learning a subject in detail so that even when intelligent people challenge me, I know the answer. I know that I am right. And I can explain the answer perfectly. Mastering a topic at the level is a thrill for me. I love it. The students here hold me to task. They are paying customers who want a good product. They push me to know the topics I teach cold.

I learn lots from my students. Hearing them talk about the problems they face in the real world, in their work environment, is useful, especially since the students are so diverse. Some have been in the military, others in industry—all sorts of industries. We have students who are or have been professional athletes. They are involved in all sorts of different activities. Listening to them apply economic principles to their experiences is fantastic. I often receive emails from students discussing these applications: “I saw a great soccer game showing what you explained about game theory. Here you go.” Their experiences benefit future classes because those experiences become examples I use in future classes. I view the whole educational process as a virtuous cycle:  I learn from the students who learn from me.

Because the students are from diverse backgrounds, teaching them is also challenging. Some students majored in economics as undergraduates. Others have never previously studied the subject. Yet I have to craft lectures that are interesting and engaging for students across this continuum. This requirement challenges me, and sometimes worries me, in part because students have different preferences. Some want only global examples whereas others prefer U.S. ones. Some students want heavy theory and mathematics; others would prefer none. Designing interesting, engaging lecturers balancing these different needs and preferences is challenging.



8.   Many scholars write books to share their research results and ideas with broader readership. Do you plan to pen a book in the not-too-distant future? If so, please tell us about it.

To be perfectly honest, I have a ten-year research agenda ahead of me that I need to complete first. At this point in my career, starting a book does not make any sense. I might also add that I would only write one if I had something I felt were important enough to write about, ideas that would have an impact on government and industries. I have seen people rush to write books, but I would only do so if I felt I could make a contribution, helping governments set better policies. Publishing a book is not high on my list of current priorities, but if you ask me again in ten years, I might respond differently.



9.   How would you evaluate behavioral economics? To what extent are you interested in incorporating psychological theories into your own research?

Behavioral economics has been popular for the last ten years or so, and there have been a variety of advances. I think behavioral economics is interesting as a field. The challenge lies in the lack of a model. We do not yet have a good model, a comprehensive theory of all the individual differences. The lack of a model makes it frustrating for me to work with behavioral economics from a research perspective. I often joke that this is the reason I like to study firms:  They tend to be more rational. For this reason, doing research on them is easier than on people.

However, behavioral economic issues are relevant for managers. My students often make comments like, “I may not be perfectly rational, so why would I make that choice?” However, I have only done about half a lecture on this still-young field for my students because I spend most of the time discussing the rational economic behavior of firms. I think behavioral economics is important, useful, and interesting, but it’s not my area. I am hoping that other sharp researchers develop a unified theory of behavior economics soon. It would become a great toolbox for future research. Currently, the conclusion of behavioral economics seems to be “we are not all rational.”



This is my recent Kindle book with colleague Dr. Yuzo Sugimoto. It presents real English dialogues introducing American culture with supplemental usage problems for standardized test preparation.